Thursday, December 10, 2015

Inflation and UE in Japan

Two graphs presented by Scott Sumner

First Japanese GDP deflator






Quick eyeball description.  Inflation from 1981-1993, no inflation from 1994-1998, deflation from 1999-2013 and inflation from 2014-2015.

Japanese UE rate

Quick eyeball description.  Declining UE from 2005-2007, flat UE from 2007-2008, rising UE in 2009, declining UE from 2010-2015.



What is the correlation between inflation and the UE rate with the information given?  We have two periods of declining UE rates, both of which occur mostly under deflation, one period of rising UE, under deflation, and one period of inflation with declining UE (eyeballing looks like the same trend in decline that it had under the previous deflationary regime).


What happens if we take UE under the full range given to us by the GDP deflator graph?
Now we also have rising UE from 1981-1988 alongside inflation.  In a matrix of inflation, deflation, rising UE and falling UE there are 4 combinations (ignoring flat for both).  We see all 4 combinations over a 35 year period in these graphs.
Correlation between inflation and UE in Japan = none. 

What is Sumner's conclusion about Abenomics? 
I thought the monetary “arrow” would be a modest success, as they were on the right track but not doing enough.  In fact, so far the monetary arrow has been an overwhelming success, beyond almost anyone’s wildest dreams.
 Which leads to obvious questions: who gets credit for the drop in the UE rate from 2010-2012 (Abe's party wins an election in late 2012) under deflationary pressures?  Why is there no apparent change in the decline in UE rate after Abe is elected?  Or again after the CB started targeting 2% inflation? 

Wednesday, May 6, 2015

Low Interest Treasuries

Here is a typical description of a liquidity trap from an economist

Think of a liquidity trap as a situation where investors view central bank money and treasury debt as perfect substitutes. Such a condition likely never holds exactly in reality, but that's neither here nor there. Empirical relevance is possible even if liquidity trap conditions hold approximately. In any case, if money and bonds are close to perfect substitutes, then the composition of total government debt (between money and bonds) has little economic significance (in the same way that the composition of the money supply between $5 and $10 bills does not matter).
 This is just one of many examples out there discussing the implication of very low interest rates on bonds.  What I have never seen from these same people is a discussion on when exactly, or even generally bonds become money-like, and the implications on evaluating monetary policy prior to 2008.  I am going to run through this pretty sloppily, the assumptions and numbers here are to get a feel for the scale, and not to put a final number or even range on it.

I doubt that anyone would defend the position that bonds are 0% like money at 0.001% and an almost perfect money substitute at 0.000%.  Nor do I think that anyone would defend the position that bonds with a 20% yield are good money substitutes (though under some conditions they might be, but for now I am talking about the US from 2000-present). 

So my first assumption is that the moneyness of bonds starts to become significant around a 2.5% yield.  This is somewhat arbitrary, but a defensible starting position.  The Fed has an inflation target around 2%, which makes bonds paying that rate or less (expected) losers in real terms.  If there is an inflection point where bonds start to become more like money the expected inflation rate is a reasonable guess as to that point.  I use 2.5% because inflation had typically been above 2%, and because it makes it nice and easy with the fed dropping rates by a quarter point at a time along with assumption #2. 

Second assumption, debt is distributed pretty evenly by duration.  Short term bonds should cover 8-10% of all debt in the US, and only publicly held debt matters for this exercise.  I am going to use 10%, and the US had a publicly held debt of between 3.5 and 4.0 Trillion dollars from 2000-2003.  So 3.75 trillion for an average. 

So starting with bonds being 0% money at 2.5%+ and becoming 100% money at 0%, each drop of 0.25% represents 10% more "moneyness" (yes, laziness and linearness, they go arm in arm)- which effects 10% of the total debt.  So a 0.25% drop below 2.5% means 1% of total publicly held debt becomes money.  1% is 35-40 billion dollars. 

Using the Federal funds rate (monthly data)- October 2001 was the first breach of the 2.5% fake barrier since 1962.  The rate fell to 1%, so the BotE calculation implies a 210-240 billion dollar increase in the money supply over that time period.  To put that in perspective the adjusted monetary base went up by less than 200 billion dollars during that time period.  This effect, if real and within half an order of magnitude of this calculation would mean the Fed loosened during this period 2 to 4 times as much as conventional estimates. 

What else does it imply though?  Well when the Fed started raising rates in Mid 2004 they were tightening twice as much as conventional estimates (until the rate broke 2.5%, then it magically stopped). 

The real kicker though comes in 2008 when the Fed again drops below 2.5%, because total government debt was 50% higher in 2008 than in 2003 the effect would be ~50% higher.  So a 50-60 billion dollar increase per 0.25% rate drop.  By the time the Funds rate was bouncing around below 0.25% in December 2008 this effect would have added $600 billion dollars or so in "money" in addition to the $800 billion or so the monetary base increased.

The final implication is even more dramatic as federal debt held by the public has shot up to almost $13 trillion in 2014.  That would be another $700 trillion in money "created" on top of the $1.6 trillion added to the monetary base.

This seems to me to be a very straight forward consequence of the idea that bonds and money are excellent substitutes near the zero bound.  You can argue against some of the methods I used, for instance you could disagree with using the federal funds rate instead of actual US Treasury rates, or disagree with the %s used.  Those disagreements would only effect the timing and magnitude of the loosening/tightening, and not the core concept. 


Thursday, March 5, 2015

Information

One thing that bugs me to no end is the generic assumption that we can tease out tons of information from prices, this is probably mostly a rant piece so feel free to ignore (all zero people that read this blog).

Point 1.  You can only figure out default probability by comparing interest rates to some neutral asset.  Say, for example, you wanted to guess at the implied default rate of a bond put up to build a new casino in Vegas.  You take that bond and subtract out the interest rate for a T-Bill of similar maturity and you have a decent idea of what that bonds default rate is relative to the T-Bill.  This ONLY works because you are assuming the failure of 1 hotel in Vegas doesn't cause a noticeable change in the probability of default of the US.  Duh.  Everyone knows this.  Except tons of people don't follow this advice when discussing the default rate of T-Bills.  I have read, in various comments and blog posts, probably dozens of different times some variation of "the market doesn't seem worried about a US default seeing as they are only demanding x% interest rates to compensate".  So here is the question- what would you want to hold if there was a default in Treasuries?  Cash?  Where are we putting trillions of dollars in cash, because the US banking system is backed both explicitly and implicitly by US bonds.  If there was a default the FDIC would not be able to cover any substantial failures without turning to the treasury who wouldn't be able to borrow. 

Point 2.  A market price only tells you about what market participants think.  The TIPS spread only tells you about inflation expectations of people that actively buy treasuries, and who think that TIPS are an excellent way to play high inflation expectations.  If Gold cranks generally aren't buying TIPS when they think inflation is around the corner, they buy gold.  It doesn't matter if you think they are nuts or not, if you call you position "market monetarism" but exclude portions of people you disagree with, guess what- you should be dropping the "market" portion of your name. 

Monday, February 9, 2015

Micro vs Macro

The difference between studying micro- and macro-economics is the difference between being easily influenced and easily influencing others.  In micro-economic studies you are looking at a small scale event, and so you can generally assume that most variables don't change much due to the event because if its small size.   Micro could be called the "all else equal" discipline because the stability of the greater economy allows you to isolate variables.  The converse is also true, you wouldn't want to conduct a microeconomic study in France from 1938-1950 because world events would dominate the data.  Macro studies should be focused on the opposite, macro events are (by definition) large and impactful, and thus macro investigation should be mostly about the feedback relationships caused by the event.  The obvious differences in how an event should be analyzed due to its size doesn't stop the overwhelming majority of experts on macro from using the tools that should be reserved for micro.

In a recent blog post Paul Krugman "investigates" the question- will a recently strong dollar be a drag on the US economy?  Let us skip to the last few paragraphs of the piece (emphasis mine).
In case #1, everyone sees the relative strength of US spending as temporary – either they see it as a one-time blip that will go away, or they expect the rest of the world to exhibit a similar surge in demand in the not-too-distant future. In that case the dollar doesn’t move, and the bulk of the demand surge stays in the US.
In case #2, everyone sees the strength of US spending relative to the rest of the world as more or less permanent. In that case the dollar rises sharply, effectively sharing the rise in US demand more or less evenly around the world. It’s important to note, by the way, that this is not just ordinary leakage via the import content of spending; it works via financial markets and the dollar, and happens even if the direct leakage through imports is fairly small.
So, what’s actually happening? The dollar is rising a lot, which suggests that markets regard the relative rise in US demand as a fairly long-term phenomenon – which in turn should mean that a lot of the rise in US demand ends up benefiting other countries. In other words, the strong dollar probably is going to be a major drag on recovery.

 You can read the rest of the piece to see that I am not taking anything out of context, but I will note that Krugman is specifically referring to a case where a country is at the zero lower bound to avoid any accusations of unfairness, though I don't think the distinction matters here.

Let me demonstrate the absurdity of the conclusion by extending the two scenarios into a future a little bit more while holding everything else constant.  In scenario 1 demand in the US rises relative to the rest of the world, and then falls back.  One way that this could happen is that there is an increase in demand in the US, with world demand staying at the same level, and then US demand declining.  Keynesians have a word for the decrease in demand, recession.  In the second scenario we would concluded that continually rising demand would cause a continually strengthening dollar.  Keynesians also have a word that starts with the letter R to describe a sustained increase in demand, recovery!  It gets stranger for the longer and stronger the growth in demand was in the US the stronger the US dollar would become, and so the more of a drag the dollar would become on recovery.  To sum up this position as succinctly as possible- a recovery (increase in US demand) will be "a major drag on recovery".

This is the extent to which micro style analysis (holding most of the world constant) can pervert your thinking in application to macro events.  Keynesians are probably the most frequent culprits of this type of error as their approach is extremely model heavy. Everything has to be aggregated and everything has to be expressed in a 1+1 = 2 type of way.  When their model predictions fail they are left reverting to "the world is different because of X", under condition A we use model B, under condition C we use model D, as we see in this piece as we swap from a normal time to a period at the zero bound.  What is conveniently ignored  is that policy makers lean more heavily Keynesian (not Keynesian enough! the cry always goes) than any other direction.  It is the adherence to model B that leads to the conditions where it no longer works.

Wednesday, February 4, 2015

Nick Rowe gets lost taking a shortcut

Nick Rowe is like the anti Tyler Cowen- lots of content, no links, tons of interaction with his commentors which explains why he will never be (wildly) popular. Marginal Revolution is the something for everyone (well everyone who likes econ) blog while Rowe's posts at Worthwhile Canadian Initiative are for everyone that wants to spend half an hour thinking about his simplest post- and trying to write a 2 line intro to a piece has totally distracted me and now I am looking up econ blog rankings.... why am I so easily dis . . .  hey look a ball!

So Nick Rowe has a post - if you want to get the specifics you should read his blog. I mean honestly if you aren't related to me and simply trying to monitor my mental health state surreptitiously (I am on to you!) you shouldn't be reading this blog unless are already reading his.  So let me skip beyond a summary and get to a point already.
But that's not all there is to it. Because the demand for my autographs will also depend on whether people expect they will appreciate or depreciate in value.
Suppose the current total market value of my autographs is $100 (10 autographs at $10 each). If I want to shrink it to $50, all I need do is threaten to produce autographs in unlimited amounts if the total market value ever rises above $50. And I must be prepared to carry out my threat, to make it credible. By printing autographs at a faster rate I make them depreciate in value at a faster rate, which reduces the demand for my autographs, which reduces the total market value of my autographs.
And then later
Bits of paper with my signature are just like bits of paper plastic or silicon with the signatures of Stephen Poloz and Carolyn Wilkins (Governor and Deputy Governor of the Bank of Canada). Except we measure prices of everything else in the latter and not in the former, so a fall in the price of my autographs is equivalent to a rise in the price of everything else in terms of their autographs. And we use the latter but not the former as a medium of exchange (which is why the latter have a demand curve where quantity and price are inversely proportional).
As it happens I was recently talking to someone who was concerned with high inflation in the future, and his reaction to this worry is to increase his demand for money right now.  Crazy, right?  No, because he is on the verge of retiring and in his view dying with a million dollars in the bank is a far better outcome than living for 5 years broke, struggling and feeling like a burden on his family.  In financial terms he has asymmetrical risk.

Much of our modern economy is exposed to asymmetrical risk, banks in particular are heavily exposed to the risk of future inflation.  Lets say as CEO of a bank you are hosting a huge party to celebrate $100 billion dollars in loans, when a top financial analyst run into the room and whispers in your ear that he has crunched the numbers and, gasp, inflation is going to be 2 percentage points per year higher than you thought over the next 10 years. What, besides snide remarks about run on sentences, is your plan for future loans?  Obviously making more loans at the current rate is out of the question since you are just increasing your exposure, and you will need a healthy cushion so you can maintain your reserve ratio, and finally you want a large cash hoard to loan out after inflation has hit (and interest rates have gone up) to rebuild the portfolio and cover the losses on loans made recently.

What does this look like from a CBs point of view?   Demand for money seems to have risen, so now the CB prints (or promises to) more money, which should push our bank to expect even more inflation, so it hoards more.

What happens in the economy?  Mortgages are harder to come by, either they have higher interest rates or they are simply unavailable.  Either way home prices decline and people who are selling homes either have to pay for two places to live or take a lower price, so their consumption is likely to be cut back to compensate (people buying at "lower" prices but higher interest rates aren't gaining much, if any, purchasing power, and those that want to buy but can't- its difficult to say).  Now we have a liquidity crisis because the bank is hoarding and we have lower measured inflation due to lower consumption (and possibly just through lower housing prices depending on how housing is included), so what is a CB to do?  Why, print more!   Promise more inflation!  Scare the bank more!  Make the bank hoard more!

I put an unstated assumption in here to make it work- that inflation can happen with a lag.  Nick Rowe puts the opposite assumption- that inflation is close to immediate (we both simplified a lot as well).   The point here isn't to aruge that my scenario is correct and his isn't, it is to identify that Nick's is dependent on simplification, that there isn't a lag in inflation, that there aren't third parties exposed to moves in the prices of his autographs and a whole bunch of other (likely) things.

Monday, February 2, 2015

IOR part 2

IOR 1 is here

In IOR 1 I laid out a pretty basic outline for when interest on reserves would be inflationary/contractionary, here I am thinking about practical implications for Fed policy.

If the Fed wants to use IOR as a tightening tool we have to expect that inflation or expectations of future inflation are getting to high.  Since the Fed seems perfectly happy with inflation in the 2-2.5% range I assume it would take something more than that for them to try out a new program on a large scale (the Fed is frequently viewed as conservative, especially by MMs).  Also for it to impact inflation the transmission of price increases has to be primarily through bank loans, otherwise paying interest on reserves won't accomplish much if anything.

in 2014 the Fed remitted ~80 billion to the Treasury, and excess reserves are currently over 2.5 trillion dollars. Going back to IOR #1- IOR should expand the MS when payments exceed Fed profits (ie remittences)- so if the Fed tries to tighten with IOR it will start fighting itself with those ratios around a 3.2% interest rate.  The Fed isn't jacking up IOR anything soon according to its guidance, and its remittances have been relatively flat since 2010 while excess reserves have increased at over 300 billion per year during that span.  5 more years of those trends (Japanese "lost decade" range) and the Fed would be facing issues at a 2% rate, and another 5 years to 1.5%.  Japan is currently 25 years into an environment like this, which would put the Fed in a pickle before it hit the 1% mark.

Point #2 is that IOR is only effective if the rate is high enough to convince banks not to lend.  Well if inflation is significantly above 3% then deposit rates should be in that range, so banks are unlikely to willingly take less than that from the Fed to lend* as they would slowly be bleeding out even while getting "free money" from the Fed.

This isn't a definitive treatment, but it is a substantial blow to those who think the Fed should and could push for a return to trend growth.  A big push to get multiyear inflation (or nGDP if you prefer) above the historical trend to bring the curve back up is likely to put the Fed in position where its attempts to tighten lead to a larger money supply- and unlike most of QE a MS in which it holds no claims against.  If inflation were to push into the 4-5% range the Fed would be playing with fire and would risk losing control of the MS.

*The effective rate the Fed has to set to curtail lending will likely be higher than the deposit rate as the portfolios of banks will be heavily weighted to loans made over the past 5+ years with extremely generous terms to borrowers, and banks will have to make up those losses in the event of a substantial increase in rates.

IOR

I have the impression that a few of the blogs I read regularly have offhandedly remarked that interest on reserves is contrationary.  The logic being that if you pay banks enough to hold money they will do so at the expense of lending money.  Let us look at this from a couple of angles.

From a base perspective IOR is inflationary.  If the Fed pays banks not to make loans those banks then distribute that money to their employees/bondholders/equity holders.  Of course the Fed is an insanely profitable institution- remitting tens of billions to the Treasury each year- if total IOR payments are less than or equal to those received by the Treasury then the Fed doesn't have to print, they just distribute those dollars differently, but when total IOR payments are > that line the Fed must increase the MS to make them.  Furthermore that would be a permenant increase.  The important ratios would be the IOR rate vs the rate on the assets on the Fed's balance sheet and the balance sheet to total reserves.  

From an incentive perspective IOR would "encourage" banks to hold deposits and so it is contractionary in terms of velocity.  How impactful this would be is dependant on the relative size of IOR vs the market rate, and the direction the market rate is moving.  If IOR is making banks less likely to make loans you would expect rates to increase until they felt that they were compensated for passing on IOR.  At 0.25% it is highly unlikely that IOR is discouraging major investments, just as a 0.25% reduction in the funds rate is unlikely to generate a large amount of economic activity.  With rates hanging out at or near historical lows since IOR was initiated it is highly unlikely that it has had a significant contractionary effect.  

There is a 3rd possible angle- liquidity.  Lets say banks didn't want to loan at all- economic conditions are deteriorting quickly enough that the likelyhood of default becomes the dominant factor over opportunity cost. If a bank was in this position they would not expect to make any loans at any price (higher interest rates could increase default probability more than the extra points are worth- hypothetically).  In this scenario a bank would be tempted to lay off employees, and shutter locations.  If conditions improved and loans flowed freely again then banks would scramble to catch up, rehire and retrain employees.  IOR could, possibly, give them enough return to retain them and allow banks to react to positive news faster.  

This third angle, along with just establishing the precedent and mechanisms for IOR, is probably what the Fed had in mind when they instituted such a paltry percent.  Just enough to allow banks to maintain operations without really holding back any quality loans.  

Friday, January 23, 2015

Money, huh, what is it good for?

There are basically two ways that money is useful- you can spend it (duh) and you can not spend it (huh?  duh?).  These two functions are usually called the unit of account (spending) and a store of value (not spending).  The invention, and wide spread acceptance, of money is truly a wonderful thing, and is possibly the second most important discovery of all time for humans (fire rules!).

Now money is fairly unique as a medium of account.  Within a currency zone, say the US, the national currency does the majority of the heavy lifting (yes exceptions exist) when it comes to transactions.  

On the other hand there are many competitors for stores of value, and I am not just talking about gold.  Stocks, bond, and precious metals can all, under the right circumstances, be vehicles for storing and increasing wealth. The closer to zero that interest rates drop the less of a distinction there is between cash and other "stores of value".  This is all basic, generally accepted, stuff.

So the question is how does QE work?  When a CB prints and swaps out dollars for bonds- be they government or private- they are swapping one store of value for another.  If there was a shortage of cash and people wanted to make purchases but were cash (or liquidity) constrained then you could make a case that by swapping cash for bonds provides a functional value to the economy and that money will move around.  But what evidence is there for a lack of cash in the system?  M2 velocity has been declining since the late 90s-

If people wanted money so that they could buy things and there was a shortage of money then velocity should shoot way the eff up, not down.  If people want money to hold onto because the opportunity cost of other stores of value has declined then this is the type of graph you would expect.  Of importance note how velocity has declined since the end of the recession as well as the fact that the decline started prerecession.  If anyone tries to paint this recession as being CAUSED BY declining velocity, as I recall some did, they have a lot of 'splaining to do. 

These are really pretty basic ideas in economics I know, but they fundamentally explain how the ECB can promise to buy AT LEAST 1 trillion Euros worth of bonds and nudge expected inflation around 0.2%

 OK- back to what I said about stores of value- I mentioned PMs, but funnily enough there really isn't any evidence of them being a store of value since the US dollar went off the gold standard in 1913 (haha!) it has been highly volatile and it is not at all appropriate to call PMs a store of value.  So what?  Well if gold isn't a store of value, and gold isn't used as a medium of account then central banks can force inflation buy buying gold.*

The irony here is delicious on all sides.  If central banks started buying gold to push inflation they would be making it more and more like a store of value, making it more like money, after decades of fighting to make it less like money.  On the other hand gold bugs (in recovery myself) look at purchases of gold by central banks and say "look at Russia/China buying gold" they are going to create a stronger currency that can someday compete with the US dollar. 
 

*Why gold and not something else?  Anything else would do (like oil, wheat or silver) but those things are either far less practical to store or are used heavily in industry or both.  Purchasing them in large amounts would not only drive up prices but also limit supply which would cause negative shocks to the economy.

Monday, January 19, 2015

Great News!

Scott Alexander thinks that

I was originally confused why they published this result instead of heading to online casinos and becoming rich enough to buy small countries, but it seems that it’s a very simplified version of the game with only two players. More interesting, the strategy was reinforcement learning – the computer started with minimal domain knowledge, then played poker against itself a zillion times until it learned everything it needed to know. Everyone who thinks that AI is nothing to worry about, please think very carefully about the implications of a stupid non-generalized algorithm being able to auto-solve a game typically considered a supreme test of strategy and intellect. (Bold mine)

He also says in the comments

The problem is that in forty years, someone will be saying “Yes, conquering Europe used to be seen as a supreme test of strategy and intellect, but now that computers can do it the real test of original thinking is something less tractable. Like Go.”

Lets talk a little rational behavior.  If poker is "solved" and you can't win anymore then the best thing to do is not play poker online anymore.  Pretty straightforward right?  How about for computers?  Well if it is solved then playing online should mean you only play against other near perfect computers and you will both lose to the rake- which means computers also shouldn't play online unless they are for sure playing against people.

Lets extend it- if war in Europe is "solved" by a computer logically no human should ever start a war in Europe again.  Peace in our time!  Ok, so a computer could win a war in Europe, but with a computer on the other side it should be very wary of starting war since war carries an extremely high rake- way higher than an online casino.  In fact it is so well established that trading > war as an economic fact that turning war over to computers that had figured it out should lead to peace in our time!

Honestly this analysis is pretty weak sauce since winning and losing are defined by the rules of the game.  If you define winning as "no Jews left in Europe" then war would go from no chance to 100% chance really quickly, so you have a framing question still to worry about.  Still the optimist can present an incredibly strong case- once computers have solved all games and are pitted against one another the only games that they would choose to participate in are positive sum games.... you know, like trade and technological advancement!  Given a choice between a game neither can win or a game you both can win the only immediately obvious reasons to pick the former are things like xenophobia or ego. 

I, for one, welcome our new robot overlords! 

Saturday, January 17, 2015

A silly/scary thought experiment on the Swiss Franc

The ECB is generally expected to launch a QE program sometime next week (late Jan 2015), last week the SNB dropped its price ceiling relative to the Euro.  What would happen if the SNB had retained the peg and the ECB started a large QE program?

1.  QE should devalue the Euro
2.  The Franc then rises vs the Euro
3.  The SNB steps in and prints Francs to buy Euros and maintain the peg.

Simple, right?  But we totally skipped WHAT the ECB is buying.  What if they decided to pursue QE by purchasing Francs?  What kind of mad world do we live in if that happens?

1.  ECB prints Euros to buy Francs
2.  Francs rise double fast (purchases increase the number of Euros AND decrease the number of Francs availible)
3.  SNB steps in, prints 2X (more than 1X as many, not necessarily 2X) as many Francs to maintain peg.
4.  SNB purchases pull Euros out of the market sterilizing their QE.
5.  ECB prints Euros and buys Francs
Repeat steps 2-5

If both banks honor their commitments and react reasonably quickly to price changes we would (expect) to see the Franc hit 1.20 and stick like glue.  With both sides having infinite ammunition in this fight there is no logical end in sight.  What should happen to those currencies compared to other currencies?  Other than some froth early on I think you can make a case for nothing (I think you could also make a case for nothing followed by complete collapse).  No new Euros will functionally hit the market before being snapped up by the Swiss and no new Francs will enter flows, they will be stocked up by the ECB. 

Is the effect really neutral though?  I think perhaps not.  In the end the banks will lose some control over their own currency and gain some control over the other parties currency.  If these two entities were of equal size then the effects would be a wash, but because the ECB represents a much more massive economic conglomerate than Switzerland the relative number of Francs it would have to put on the market to alter the value of the Swiss currency is much smaller.  In this game of chicken the Swiss would be giving up sovereignty (conservatively) ten times as quickly as the ECB would be. 

Don't believe me?  Imagine the ECB initiates QE equal to 100% of Swiss GDP (lets pretend everything ends up 1:1 nicely for simplicity) by buying Francs- the SNB expands its balance sheet by 100% of GDP by purchasing Euros to sterilize this action.  Now the ECB turns around and uses those Francs to buy US dollars.  What happens to the value of the Franc with around 800 billion newly minted ones hitting the market and 800 billion dollars getting soaked up?  Unless the Swiss want massive inflation (not 2-5% inflation but double and maybe triple digit inflation) they have to dump some of their holdings- which are overwhelmingly Euro denominated- to soak up those Francs and the Euro should depreciate vs the Franc (and also vs the Dollar). 

There is a lie floating around the ether that a CB can control its own currency with enough gumption.  That may be true (its probably not) but it immediately becomes false when a country pegs to another currency, and becomes false and really dangerous when it comes to pegging vs a much larger currency. 

If we combine this post with one from earlier today we have a rational explanation for the Swiss abandoning the peg.  That little (ie 20-30 billion francs) increase in late 2014 in SNB holdings indicate that the Swiss had not convinced the market of its commitment to maintain the peg.  To match a big QE program from the ECB the Swiss would be giving up substantial autonomy for future moves.  Even if the ECB wasn't specifically buying up Francs it would still be the major buyer of paper when Francs were flooding the market.  Either directly or indirectly the ECB would be major players in the Franc's future. 

Dude, where's my credibility? Swiss bank edition

having in effect thrown away its credibility – in today’s world, the crucial credibility central banks need involves, not willingness to take away the punch bowl, but willingness to keep pushing liquor on an abstemious crowd – it’s hard to see how the SNB can get it back.- Paul Krugman

 It’s stupid to throw away 3 1/3 years of credibility.  I won’t even say “hard-earned credibility,” as it was pathetically easy to peg the SF for 3 1/3 years. - Scott Sumner

There is a school of thought, and its the mainstream one, that a central bank can manage its currency on expectations and credibility alone.  The theory goes basically like this- if the Swiss Bank promises to prevent the Franc from appreciating above the 1.20 mark against the Euro then you would be a fool to sell your Euros for 1.19 Francs since as soon as the SNB gets wind of this transaction they will print Francs and buy Euros until the exchange rate hits 1.20 again.  Armed with perfect knowledge of future price moves (in this case only in one direction) exchanges should never threaten the peg.  The single obstacle to overcome then is to convince the market that you are truly and surely going to stick to that peg, come hell or high water.  Once the market believes you you just sit back and listen for the accolades. 

The SNB set a ceiling to its value relative to the Euro more than 3 years ago, in that time it has basically doubled its balance sheet in nominal terms in moves that exceed (again nominally) the amount it expanded its balance sheet from 2006 to 2010 when the world was in some serious fucking turmoil.  I don't want this blog to have tons of cursing in it (I need my supply for every day life) but I want to stress what so many seem to gloss over.  2006-2010 was absolutely craziness at times.  The "recovery" of the last few years has been extremely tame in terms of volatility, and yet the Swiss bank has added more "assets" to its balance sheet than during the most economically stressful time in the past 80 years.

In fact as of late 2014 the SNB was STILL expanding its balance sheet, sure that little spike looks pidley in comparison to the other moves but it represents tens of billions of dollars (or Francs, or Euros) worth of purchases.

So here is my question- if for 3 years the Swiss has pumped seemingly unending amounts of Francs into the system to defend its half-peg why didn't they have any real credibility?  If a CB is truly in control of its own currency then how freaking long does it take and how many HUNDREDS OF BILLIONS OF currency units does it have to go through to generate the mythological track where markets don't even test their resolve?  This is a rhetorical question, this post is simply to point out that everyone who says the Swiss have given up "credibility" have frankly failed to establish that they every had any, and are simply working on the assumption.  Their models are suspect, their predictions are suspect and their analysis is suspect. 

Things are happening in this world (I didn't even mention the negative interest rates) that have never been tried before, we cannot coast on old assumptions that sounded right, the evidence that they are wrong is small, but growing. 

Friday, January 16, 2015

What's in a name? Bubbles.

This is more in a back and forth between this blog and Idiosyncratic Whisk.

First we have to discuss definitions of a bubble before we can move on to talk about if housing in the 90s through aughts qualifies.  Most people take for granted that housing was a bubble so I appreciated that there are (apparently quite bright given his blog) dissenters like Kevin questioning some huge assumptions.  For my money something is a bubble not because it deviates from historical norms, or because its price increases are "to large"-  I think what makes a bubbles is the fact (or threat) that a change in the sign of growth (not only from positive to negative, but also from positive to zero, or from zero to negative) causes a feedback loop that pushes prices down.  Ponzi schemes are classic bubbles- once new investors cannot be corralled into keeping payouts high the whole thing disappears as one person pulling out their money causes lower returns which causes others to pull out their money.  The fact that a person cannot pull their money out of Social Security (at least not easily) prevents it from this Ponzi like collapse, even though the other fundamental aspects are the same. 

I will summarize Kevin's position here- he has written a ton about it so I won't do it justice in nuance but the general gist is that with very low nominal rates of interest it makes sense to borrow large amounts (to lever up) in exchange for the cash flow (in this case the implied rent).  This is similar- but definitely not identical- to the idea that was floated during the boom that house prices were being supported by lower interest rates because lower rates meant lower costs of purchase and so a person could purchase "more house" (ie a higher prices house) for the same monthly payment.  Kevin also provides a timely quote in the comments of one of his recent posts

I prefer to begin analysis of homeownership by thinking of home values as an all-cash investment. There are ways that mortgages might effect market prices, but those are tweaks from the all-cash intrinsic value.

 This is a major point of disagreement for me.  By treating home ownership as an all-cash investment he eliminates the roles of banks, and banks and homeowners have very different risk profiles, and it is this risk profile where his analysis falls short.

Banks have two risks when they loan, interest rates and default rates.  Because they borrow short and lend long an increase in interest rates freezes the majority of their income at lower rates while increasing their operating costs.  Default risk is simply the risk that the borrower cannot pay back the loan, in which case the bank seizes the house and sells it off to recover as much of the loan as they can.  All banks use models that assume some default rate and some reduced sale price (frequently around 80% of market value) to calculate expected losses on loans.  This creates a potential double whammy if interest rates increase as banks face stiffer costs to keep their capital requirements up to snuff while also having to raise more to cover larger losses on defaults (higher interest rats -> lower prices -> lower recovery %s).

What can happen on the other side of the ledger is very interesting.  In the case of a fall in interest rates, and subsequent rise in house prices, is an apparent decrease in the risk of bank loans.  This happens because most of a bank's book (at least economy wide) is based on loans already made.  If prices increase 5% then a banks recovery rate (if it stays stable at 80% of market value) will now be 84% of the original purchase price for all previous purchases.  Lets say a bank's book is 10% loans made recently and 90% made in the past, then every price increase reduces a bank's default risk by 9 times that of the risk new loans carry at the higher price.  Every new marginal borrower can be riskier than the previous average in the bank's eyes.

Here we can describe a positive feedback look pushing prices higher in which banks appear to be acting sanely.  Higher prices mean a lower risk profile for the bank, which allows slightly riskier loans, this pulls more home buyers into the market which increases demand and should then push up prices and/or interest rates.  For a visual here is home ownership rates in the US
No matter the explanation for 30 years years banks rated between 63 and 66% of the population as acceptable risk as homeowners.  From 1995 to 2005 we go from ~64% (roughly the 30 year average) to 69%- more than 3 percentage points higher than the previous high shown.  The US had between 105-110 million households in 2005 so that 3-5% rise over the historical average means that over 10 years there were 3.1-5.5 million more homeowners than you would have predicted in 1995.  This HO rate increase roughly matches when price increases started to take off in earnest

Going back to my (quick and dirty) definition of a bubble is a feedback loop once we have a change in the sign of prices.  First I want to say that banks are not run by idiots, and the people writing models that project things like default risk and recovery rates are not idiots, but the way most models are written is based on historical data.  If default rates have hovered around 1% for 50 years, a number close to 1% is going into your model, if recovery rates are 80% over that span, and number close to 80% is going into that model.  Models like these tend to break down around historical anomalies, not just because of different dynamics at those points but because the data leading up to those points is usually incorporated into their models.  When loans were made in 2004 the price increases of 1995-2003 were going to be a natural part of estimating risk.

In my narrative we have moved the price of housing up and the quality of homeowners in terms of default risk down.  Implied in that second part is the fact that the remaining pool of potential homeowners is of lower quality than the historical average.  Also implied is that the lower quality a homeowner you are (if you have bought a house) the closer to the peak purchase price of was the timing of your purchase.  Now a change in the price signal- even just from positive to no growth- will cause a spiral.  Defaults will be at the high end of historical averages (and maybe higher) and the cost of those purchases will also be the highest of those on the books.  Recovery rates fall because the pool of available buyers is at an all time low as well.  Now banks do some combination of raising capital and slowing loan origination to fill these losses that are on the edges (and sometimes over the edge) of their estimates and we have the potential for a spiral without a recession kick starting or amplifying it.

There are still lots of missing pieces in the puzzle, but to return to the topic- if you treat a home purchase as a cash transaction you will fail to see how a bank's risk profile changes in response to price changes. 

Now you can tell a different story with the data shown- but it basically requires the claim that either a substantial portion of the population (3-5% percent of households) went from being a poor mortgage risk to a good one, or that banks were leaving billions on the table from 1965-1995 and then suddenly came to their senses. 

Thursday, January 15, 2015

I guess I will start an econ blog

I got some sleep the past three nights, and crazy stuff is happening in the world- so lets start an econ blog that will get way off topic and degenerate into petty sniping (assuming I even get a reader) before disappearing into the ether 2 months from now. 

Kevin Erdmann at Idiosyncratic Whisk has some posts which basically argue there was no housing bubble.  Instead of arguing in the comments of Marginal Revolution I started this blog to argue across them. 

Here is a graph from IW*-



 Kevin (to familiar?) argues that there is a stable trend line of real estate value in the US- at roughly 8% annual growth.  Visually it appears stable, conceptually it is clearly not stable.  Why?  Because its a log graph, which smooths what is an exponential curve into a straightish line.  An 8% growth rate in an economy doing under 5% is probably* not going to be stable over a long period of time.  To illustrate this we can pull another graph from a different post of Kevin's on housing





Look at the blue line- that is mortgage debt to GDP.  This line is clearly not stable from around 2000 to 2006/2007. 

Kevin Asks about the 1st graph- "What looks more out of line?  The 2000's or the 2008-2014 period?"- the second graph clearly shows that "something" was out of line in the 2000s, we can disagree on what, but I can't see an argument for calling perpetual 8% growth in housing "stable" in the US.

"I argue that frictions in home supply were creating a supply shock in the 2000s, which was creating supply-based inflation."- Ok lets explore that with the data you provide plus a little context.

Housing starts


Ok- So eyeballing this chart we have much higher housing starts in the 70s/80s than we had in the 90s, but that doesn't mean a supply shock- that could just as easily mean a demand shock.  Here is a graph that points in that direction. 

Average household size in the US

The green line (US average household size) shows a leveling off after a long (60 year) decline.  Now you could argue this two ways- one is that the supply shocked limited the number of houses available and stopped the decline, but I think that is a very weak position to take given how family structure tends to work it seems pretty unlikely that the average household size should be only a hair above 2 people (and still falling). 






* I'm just linking directly to his blog instead of posting my own image, I have serious doubts that my viewership will ever reach a point where this is a problem.
**you can come up with scenarios, but they don't appear realistic in my view.